Prof. Bryan Caplan
bcaplan@gmu.edu
http://www.bcaplan.com
Econ 854
Week 4: Voter Motivation, I: Selfish, Group, and Sociotropic Voting
I.
Is the Median Voter Model Correct?
A.
In order to determine whether or not the median voter model is correct,
we must first find out "What voters want."
B.
Once we know what voters want, we can see whether actual policy
conforms to the policy preferences of the median voter.
C.
Probably the most popular account of voter motivation is that voters
are essentially self-interested.
D.
Economists typically think this, but so do many political scientists,
journalists, and "men in the street."
E.
Example #1: "Rich people vote Republican, and poor people vote
Democratic, because Republicans favor lower taxes and lower spending on
redistribution than Democrats."
F.
Example #2: "Blacks were treated worse under Jim Crow because they
weren't allowed to vote.
Politicians didn't worry about losing their votes for racist
policies."
G.
Example #3: "People
opposed to conservation laws must own stock in the timber industry."
II.
Defining the Self-Interested Voter Hypothesis (SIVH)
A.
There is a danger of tautology here: Is all behavior
"self-interested" by definition?
Was Mother Theresa self-interested?
B.
Throughout this course, I will only use the term
"self-interest" in the falsifiable, ordinary language sense of directly valuing only one's own material well-being, health, safety,
comfort, and so on. Two provisos:
1.
I interpret "people are self-interested" as "on average,
people are at least 95% selfish," not "all people are 100%
selfish."
2.
Drawing on evolutionary psychology, I interpret altruism towards blood
relatives in proportion to shared genes as self-interest.
C.
The self-interested voter hypothesis (SIVH) can then be defined as the
hypothesis that political beliefs and
actions of ordinary citizens are self-interested in the preceding sense.
III.
The Meltzer-Richards Model
A.
There is an enormous literature on the SIVH in general, and
M&R-type thinking in particular.
B.
Many of these tests - particularly those performed by economists - rely
on aggregate data. Peltzman (1985) is a classic paper in
this tradition.
C.
Examples:
1.
Are poorer ethnicities more Democratic?
2.
Are richer Congressional districts more conservative?
3.
Do SS payments rise when a higher percentage of the elderly vote?
1.
Ex: “Liberalism as a normal good”
E.
Tests on aggregate data do reveal something, but are clearly inferior
to tests that rely on data about individuals'
political beliefs and their personal characteristics (income, education, race,
age, etc.) relevant to self-interest.
1.
Political scientists pay far more attention to this sort of evidence.
F.
Amazing and important conclusion: the SIVH flops. You can find some sporadic and debatable
evidence for self-interested political beliefs, but that is about it.
G.
Consider the case of party identification. Conventional wisdom tells us that
"the poor" are Democrats and "the rich" are Republicans.
H.
In fact, the rich are only slightly more likely to be Republicans than
Democrats. (Factoids from the
SAEE).
1.
Race matters far more than income: High-income blacks are much more
likely to be Democrats than white minimum wage workers.
2.
Gender also dwarfs the effect of income: a man earning $25,000 per year
is about as likely to be a Democrat as a women earning $100,000 per year.
I.
The SIVH fails badly for individual issues as well.
1.
Unemployment policy - The unemployed not much more in favor of relief
measures.
2.
National health insurance - The rich and people in good health are
about as in favor.
3.
Busing - Childless whites are as opposed as whites with children.
4.
Crime - Crime victims and residents in dangerous neighborhoods are not
much more likely to favor severe anti-crime measures.
5.
Social Security and Medicare- The elderly are if anything slightly less
in favor than the young.
6.
Abortion - Men are slightly more pro-choice than women.
J.
The SIVH fails for government spending, but has some moderate support
for taxes.
1.
People expecting large tax savings from Proposition 13 were more likely
to support it.
2.
But recipients of government services and government employees were
about as likely to support Prop. 13 as anyone else.
K.
The SIVH fails for potential death in combat! Relatives and friends of military
personnel in
1.
Marginal evidence for SIVH - exact draft age.
L.
Best example of a strong self-interest effect: Smoking!
1.
Even though smokers and non-smokers are demographically similar,
non-smokers are much more in favor of restrictions on smoking.
2.
The heavier the smoker, the stronger the opposition.
3.
Only 13.9% of people who "never smoked" supported fewer
restrictions, compared to 61.5% of "heavy smokers."
M.
Overall, this body of evidence can only be described as
revolutionary. It is very hard to
argue against it, and it means that most of what people think and write about
politics is wrong. Thousands of
articles - and millions of conversations - have been a big waste of time
because no one bothered to examine the empirical evidence.
N.
Moreover, the empirical evidence is intuitively plausible. Are your richer friends really the
Republicans, and your poorer friends the Democrats? Can you find any connection at all? It isn't easy.
O.
Thus, tests of the Median Voter Hypothesis that assume voters are
self-interested are almost bound to fail.
Why? If voters are not
self-interested, then the failure of policy and the median voter's
self-interest to "match" proves nothing.
V.
Sociotropic Voting
A.
One major alternative to the SIVH, popular among many political
scientists, is called "sociotropic voting."
B.
Sociotropic voting means voting for policies that maximize "social
welfare" or something along those lines.
C.
Sociotropic voting is introspectively plausible and works in some
interesting empirical tests.
D.
Ex: Good economic conditions make politicians more popular. But what matters is mostly overall economic conditions, not those
of the individual respondent.
E.
But it does little to explain voter disagreement. If everyone wants to maximize
"social welfare," why don't they all vote the same way? In contrast, the SIVH has a ready
explanation for disagreement.
F.
What would the M&R model predict if voters were sociotropic? Taken literally, it predicts full
consensus.
1.
Where would the consensus lie?
It depends on the deadweight costs of taxation and welfare, the shape of
the utility function, initial endowments, etc.
VI.
Group-Interested Voting
A.
While the SIVH fails badly, there is strong evidence for group-interested voting.
B.
What's the difference? If a
policy hurts you but helps your "group," how do you vote and
think? If you go with the group,
your voting is group-interested, not self-interested.
C.
Ex: The black millionaire.
Democrats favor higher and more progressive taxes (which hurts the
millionaire a lot), but also care more about the plight of blacks (which does
virtually nothing for the millionaire; no one will discriminate against him). If self-interested, he would vote
Republican; if group-interested, he would vote Democratic.
D.
Much of the superficially plausible evidence for self-interested voting
turns out to be group-interested when you look more deeply.
E.
Ex: Jewish support for
F.
The income-party correlation is stronger in other countries than in the
1.
Interesting test to try: How many people would switch parties after
winning the Lottery?
G.
Group-interested voting gives a better theory of disagreement than
sociotropic voting. People vote
differently because the groups they belong to differ, and groups have divergent
interests.
A.
What happens if you use basic
econometrics on data from the General Social Survey to try to sort out the
determinants of party identification?
N≈49,000 for 1972-2010,
so focus on magnitudes, not t-stats.
B.
Linear
probability model:
Predict the probability of being a Democrat or being a Republican conditional
on your personal characteristics.
C.
What if you ignore ideology, and try to predict party identification
using only real income (in 1986 dollars), education (in years), race, sex
(1=male, 2=female), age, and year?
D.
[Table 1a&1b]
1.
Income. Income matters in the expected direction
for Republicans, but the magnitudes is tiny. If real income rises by 10%, P(Rep)
rises by 0.34%.
2.
Education. A year of education makes people .8
percentage-point more Republican and .5 percentage-points less Democratic. (Remember this is all years)
3.
Race. Blacks are massively more likely to be
Democrats (+35 percentage-points) and less likely to be Republicans (-22
percentage-points). The same
pattern holds – albeit more moderately – for members of
“other races.”
4.
Gender. Females are markedly more likely to be
Democrats (5.6 percentage points).
5.
Age. Older people are a little more likely to
be both Democrats and
Republicans. (Remember independents
are the omitted category).
6.
Year/1000. The population has grown less Democratic
and more Republican over time.
E.
What does all this show?
1.
Strong evidence for group-interested voting, with race being the main
group of interest.
2.
Self-interest plays a marginal role at most.
IX. Gelman on Income and Voting
X.
The SIVH Versus the Logic of Collective Action
A.
How is all this unselfish voting possible? It seems to conflict with the logic of
collective action - people sacrifice their own political interests without hope
of compensation.
B.
But this impression is misleading.
Why? Precisely because one
vote is extraordinarily unlikely to change an electoral outcome, it is very
safe to vote against your own interests!
C.
Ex: When Barbara Streisand
votes for a candidate that will charge her $2 M more in taxes, is that
equivalent to giving $2 M to charity?
D.
Of course not. Her vote
won't change the election's outcome.
If the Democrat wins, she has to pay, but he would have won - and she would have to pay - anyway! So the MC of voting Democratic is not $2
M, but $2 M times the probability that she casts the decisive vote. Even if that were a high 1-in-2 M, her
expected cost of voting Democratic would only be $1.00.
E.
The logic of collective action cuts two ways. It makes people unwilling to contribute
serious effort for political change.
But it also makes people unafraid of voting contrary to their own
interests.
Table 1a: Conditional
Probability of Being a Democrat
Table 1b: Conditional
Probability of Being a Republican