Prof. Bryan Caplan
bcaplan@gmu.edu
http://www3.gmu.edu/departments/economics/bcaplan
Econ 311
Fall, 1999
HW#4 (Please type all answers)
Change in Equilibrium Real Wage |
Inflation |
Change in Equilibrium Nominal Wage |
Nominal Fall? |
-3% |
-3% |
-6% |
Ö |
-3% |
0% |
-3% |
Ö |
-3% |
+3% |
0% |
|
-3% |
+10% |
+7% |
|
0% |
-3% |
-3% |
Ö |
0% |
0% |
0% |
|
0% |
+3% |
+3% |
|
0% |
+10% |
+10% |
|
+3% |
-3% |
0% |
|
+3% |
0% |
+3% |
|
+3% |
+3% |
+6% |
|
+3% |
+10% |
+13% |
If the real minimum wage falls below $3.00, the minimum wage has no effect and the real minimum wage is $3.00. Otherwise, the minimum wage does matter. To check whether it does, we calculate:
(i) $5.15/(1.0)10=$5.15/1=$5.15>$3.00
(ii) $5.15/(1.02)10=$5.15/1.22=$4.22>$3.00
(iii) $5.15/(1.1)10=$5.15/2.59=$1.98<$3.00
(iv) $5.15/(1.25)10=$5.15/9.31=$.55<$3.00
The Classical AS is vertical, the Keynesian is upward sloping. Output can increase in the Keynesian case because, by assumption, market prices are failing to clear markets. It cannot increase in the Classical case because, by assumption, market prices ARE clearing markets.
In the first diagram, the decline in AD moves along the SRAS curve; output and the price level fall. In the second diagram, SRAS shifts out until it equals LRAS at the new level of AD.
When money supply falls, the price of money (1/P) normally would rise (that is, P would fall!). If 1/P stays fixed, there is excess demand for money.
The supply of loanable funds decreases - fewer people make loans because there is a shortage of money. This raises the interest rate.
As interest rates rise, the money demand curve keeps falling until money demand and money supply intersect at the original 1/P.
AD increases since the money supply increases.
AD falls since the money supply decreases.
AD falls since money demand increases (credit cards, a money substitute, are now more costly to use, so some people carry more cash instead).
AD stays the same. As per the notes, if spending and the money supply stay the same, this just means that the government borrows less. That makes more loanable funds available to non-government borrowers, balancing out the fall in after-tax income.
AD stays the same. As per the notes, if taxation and the money supply stay the same, this just means that the government borrows less. That makes more loanable funds available to non-government borrowers, balancing out the fall in government spending.
If the government borrows less, the demand for loanable funds falls. Interest rates thus tend to fall. For the Fed to prevent this fall, it must reduce the money supply. The reduction of the money supply in turn makes AD fall.
(Calculate January-to-January).
Year |
Base |
% Change |
War? |
1947 |
33.612 |
-- |
|
1948 |
34.056 |
1.3 |
|
1949 |
33.257 |
-2.35 |
|
1950 |
32.991 |
-0.80 |
Ö |
1951 |
32.282 |
-2.15 |
Ö |
1952 |
35.12 |
8.79 |
Ö |
1953 |
36.362 |
3.54 |
Ö |
1954 |
36.982 |
1.71 |
|
1955 |
36.982 |
0 |
Average growth during war years=2.35%; average growth during peace years=.17%.
AD shifts out along a fixed SRAS curve.
SRAS shifts back, AD stays unchanged.
SRAS shifts out, AD stays unchanged.
SRAS shifts back, AD shifts out even more.
SRAS shifts out, AD shifts out.
The economy moves to a lower-unemployment, higher-inflation point on a fixed short-run Phillips curve.
The short-run Phillips curve shifts up; both unemployment and inflation increase.
The short-run Phillips curve shifts down; both unemployment and inflation decrease.
The short-run Phillips curve shifts up; unemployment falls, while inflation increases.
The short-run Phillips curve shifts down; unemployment falls, while inflation increases.
One thing you could do is: freeze the monetary base, redefine a "new ruble" equal in value to exactly one dollar, and legalize dollar-denominated bank accounts. Then stick to your guns - it will be a difficult task, but backing out will only make the problem worse. Of course, if you want to trick the public one last time, you could carry out these steps, wait a while, and then reverse policy.