http://www3.gmu.edu/departments/economics/bcaplan
Econ 816
Spring, 2000
HW#4 Answers
Part 1: Mathematical Problems
1. Romer, problem 9.8.
a. Since this is an RE model without exogenous uncertainty, the fact that expected inflation pe=b/a implies that actual inflation p=b/a. Therefore, .
b. The AS function in the intial period will be:
The 1-period OF is therefore:
Differentiating:
, so
Plugging into the lifetime OF yields:
Whereas if the policymaker did not defect, lifetime OF would be:
c. Find when :
Cancelling and simplifying:
This leaves us with a quadratic equation in . Solve using the quadratic formula, it can be seen that the above inequality holds if:
Simplifying:
The two critical values are thus: and .
Cooperation will then be possible so long as:
.
If , it cannot be larger than b/a, so equilibrium will exist so long as:
, implying that .
2. Romer, problem 9.9.
In all three problems, the cooperation utility remains:
a. Defection will only pay if one can defect one period, take the punishment for one period, and be better off than if one had cooperated. So compare:
to:
Simplifying:
Again solving the quadratic equation for the critical values (and simplifying!):
, so the critical values are and .
Cooperation will then be possible so long as:
.
b. This implies a two-period cost of defection. For convenience, define . Then compare:
to:
So in equilibrium:
Simplifying:
Applying the quadratic formula yields the following mess:
Which shows that with extreme punishments, you can get cooperation in more general circumstances than you can otherwise.
c. This is always an equilibrium; in each period, the policy-maker is optimizing relative to the public's actions, and vice versa.
3. Romer, problem 9.16.
ln(Mt/Pt)=a-bi+ln Yt, so:
Mt/Pt=ea-biYt
i=r+pe
The percent change in the money supply plus the inflation rate must equal the real rate of growth, so:
p=gM-gY
i=r+gM-gY
Plugging into the equation for real balances:
Mt/Pt=exp(a)exp(-b[r+gM-gY])Yt
Seigniorage equals the change in real balances:
Plugging in:
S=gM*exp(a)exp(-b[r+gM-gY])Yt
Then just maximize S wrt gM, getting:
[exp(a)exp(-b[r+gM-gY])Yt]-bgM[exp(a)exp(-b[r+gM-gY])Yt]=0
Thus:
[exp(a)exp(-b[r+gM-gY])Yt][1-bgM]=0
The first term in brackets is always positive, so the only solution is given by:
[1-bgM]=0
Implying gM*=1/b
4. Romer, problem 9.17.
a. As in the last problem, .
Define and . Then
Next, note that inflation is just the difference between nominal money growth and real money growth:
Let G be the amount of seigniorage the government spends:
, so
The money demand equation can be used to compute :
Plugging into the equation for inflation:
Now plug the above into the equation for the change in expected inflation:
, so:
Re-arranging terms:
b. In this case, you essentially get a hyperinflation - every period to have to make inflation higher to get more than S* in revenue.
c. Now in the steady state, expected inflation equals actual inflation equals the rate of money growth.