Austrian Theory of the Market Process II

 

ECON 881/Spring 2002

 

Monday 4:30-7:00

Enterprise 318

 

Professor Peter J. Boettke

 

Department of Economics

324 Enterprise Hall

703-993-1149

pboettke@gmu.edu

 

Office Hours: Tuesday 10:30-12:00; Thursday 1:00-3:00

 

 

 

This is the second course in a two-course sequence in the field of Austrian economics.   The course has been designed for those who hope to pursue a teaching and research career in which the insights of the Austrian School of Economics will play a significant role.  In other words, this course is for those who hope to pursue Austrian economics as a vocation not as an avocation.

 

We will read in and critically discuss the contributions of the Austrian School of Economics in the areas of methodology, monetary and macroeconomic theory, and market theory and the price system.  We will spend roughly four weeks in each area – the first week we be reading the “founding” arguments by Menger and Böhm-Bawerk, the second week will be devoted to reading the “classic” statements of the argument provided by Mises and Hayek, the third week we will be reading the “contemporary” statements made by the post-resurgence generation of Austrian economics, and the fourth week we will focus on reading “critical appraisals” of the Austrian tradition which exist in the literature today.  You will be expected to do all the readings before class so you can contribute to the discussion.

 

Your course grade will be based on [a] your participation in class discussions (10%), [b], essays after each course section (10%), [c] a take-home final exam (30%), and [d] an original research paper (50%).  Examples of my previous final exams can be found on-line from similar courses I have taught in the past.  This exam is designed to be comprehensive and to prepare you for the field exam in Austrian economics.  In an ideal professional world, a field in Austrian economics would not be necessary because Austrian economics is not really a field but a research program in economics similar in this regard to game theory or experimental economics.  The insights of the Austrian school can be applied to any area of research within the field of economics, political economy and social theory in general.  Unfortunately, we do not yet live in this ideal professional world and thus the field in Austrian economics is necessitated in order to provide curricular space for the advanced study of the Austrian school. 

 

I am committed to the position that the Austrian school cannot afford to be either primarily, let alone exclusively, critical of mainstream economics or historical in research orientation.  As contemporary scholars and teachers in the Austrian school tradition we must be cognizant of our differences from the mainstream of economic thought and respect the intellectual history of the disciplines of economics and political economy.  Too often, in my opinion, contemporary work in the Austrian tradition is content with criticism and historical essays.   I hope to encourage young scholars to pursue a more progressive research agenda in Austrian economics.  This requires 3 things: [1] focus less on critique and more on positive theoretical construction; [2] concentrate on the world, not necessarily the literature – seek to explain events that spark your curiosity and that of other scholars, policy makers, and intellectuals in the world and do not limit yourself to only those areas discussed in the existing literature within the economics profession; and [3] recognize that while understanding methodological issues is a necessary condition for advancing economic knowledge it is far from sufficient – economists must provide positive theoretical advancements and better explanations of the world around us otherwise their insights will be appropriately ignored by their peers.  Methodology does indeed matter, but it matters far less than what most critics of mainstream economics think it does in terms of advancing knowledge.  Accordingly, I do not encourage methodological papers for your research paper for this course.  Instead, I want you to decide on a topic early and work hard to make a contribution to theory or applied economics.  The methodological strictures in the Austrian tradition should be respected, but should not be the focus of your research endeavor.  Your papers will be judged by the only standard you should be writing for at this stage of your education --- can this paper be published in a professional journal?  In the field of Austrian economics, that means your paper could be published in either The Review of Austrian Economics or The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics.  In order to facilitate that judgment, your final draft of your paper will be due on April 29th and I will submit your papers (blind) to external referees as well as myself for assessment, an A grade will be limited to those papers, and only those papers, that are recommended for acceptance or conditional acceptance, a B grade will be assigned to those papers that receive a recommendation of revise and resubmit, and a C grade will be assigned to those papers that are rejected by the external referees and myself.  I will be available throughout the semester to discuss and read your drafts, so don’t be a stranger.

 

 

 

COURSE SCHEDULE

 

 

 

January 28, 2002                The Place of Austrian Economics in Contemporary Economic Thought

 

I. Primary Reading

 

William Baumol, “What Marshall Didn’t Know: On the Twentieth Century’s Contributions to Economics,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115 (February 2000): 1-44.

 

Peter Boettke, “Where Did Economics Go Wrong?,” Critical Review, 11 (Winter 1997): 11-64.

 

F. A. Hayek, “Economic Thought VI: The Austrian School of Economics,” International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences (New York: Macmillan, 1968).

 

Israel Kirzner, “The Austrian School of Economics,” New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (New York: Macmillan, 1986).

 

Ludwig Lachmann, “From Mises to Shackle: An Essay on Austrian Economics and the Kaleidic Society,” Journal of Economic Literature (March 1976): 54-62.

 

Fritz Machlup, “Austrian Economics,” Encyclopedia of Economics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1982).

 

Joseph Stiglitz, “The Contributions of the Economics of Information to Twentieth Century Economics,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115 (November 2000): 1441-1478.

 

 

II. Secondary Reading

 

Peter Boettke, “Formalism and Contemporary Economics," Critical Review, 12 (1998).

 

Peter Boettke, “Is There an Intellectual Market Niche for Austrian Economics?,” Review of Austrian Economics, 11 (1999): 1-4.

 

Peter Boettke and Peter Leeson, “The Austrian School of Economics: 1950-2000,” in Jeff Biddle and Warren Samuels, eds., The Blackwell Companion to the History of Economic Thought (Oxford: Basil Blackwell Publishers, 2002).

 

Daniel Hausman, “The Faults of Formalism and the Magic of Markets,” Critical Review, 12 (1998).

 

Robert Heilbroner, “The Self-Deception of Economics,” Critical Review, 12 (1998).

 

Thomas Mayer, “Boettke’s Austrian Critique of Mainstream Economics: An Empiricist’s Response,” Critical Review, 12 (1998).

 

 

 

METHODOLOGY

 

February 4, 2002               The Contributions of the ‘Founders’

 

            I. Primary Reading

 

Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, “The Historical vs. the Deductive Method in Political Economy,” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 1 (1891): 244-271.

 

Carl Menger, Principles of Economics (New York: New York University Press, 1976[1871]): 51-113; 286-288.

 

Carl Menger, Investigations into the Method of the Social Sciences with Special Reference to Economics (New York: New York University Press, 1985[1883]): 35-94; 129-159.

 

 

                II. Secondary Reading

 

Samuel Bostaph, “The Methodological Debate Between Carl Menger and the German Historicists,” Atlantic Economic Journal, 6 (September 1978): 3-16.

 

A. M. Endres, Neoclassical Microeconomic Theory: The Founding Austrian Version (New York: Routledge, 1997): 1-23.

 

 

 

February 11, 2002             The ‘Classic’ Statements

 

            I. Primary Reading

 

F. A. Hayek, Individualism and Economic Order (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980[1948]): 33-76.

 

Ludwig von Mises, Human Action (Chicago: Henry Regnery, 1966[1949]): 1-176.

 

 

                II. Secondary Reading

 

Israel M. Kirzner, Ludwig von Mises: The Man and His Economics (Wilmington, Del: ISI Books, 2001): 69-92.

 

Fritz Machlup, “The Problem of Verification in Economics,” Southern Economic Journal, 22 (1955): 1-21.

 

Fritz Machlup, “If Matter Could Talk,” in Sidney Morgenbesser, Patrick Suppes, and Morton White, eds., Philosophy, Science, and Method: Essays in Honor of Ernest Nagel (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1969):

 

Fritz Machlup, “The Inferiority Complex of the Social Sciences,” in Mary Sennholz, ed., On Freedom and Free Enterprise: Essays in Honor of Ludwig von Mises (Princeton: Van Nostrand, 1956): 161-172.

 

Fritz Machlup, “Friedrich von Hayek’s Contributions to Economics,” Swedish Journal of Economics, 76 (December 1974): 498-531, especially 520-524.

 

Stephen Parsons, “Mises, The Apriori and The Foundations of Economics: A Qualified Defense,” Economics & Philosophy, 13 (October 1997): 175-196.

 

 

 

February 18, 2002             ‘Contemporary’ Restatements

 

            I. Primary Reading

 

Robin Cowan and Mario Rizzo, “The Genetic-Causal Tradition and Modern Economic Theory,” Kyklos, 49 (3): 273-316.

 

Israel Kirzner, “On the Method of Austrian Economics,” in Edwin Dolan, ed., The Foundations of Modern Austrian Economics (Kansas City: Sheed & Ward, 1976): 40-51.

 

Ludwig Lachmann, “The Significance of the Austrian School in the History of Ideas,” in Walter Grinder, ed., Capital, Expectations and the Market Process: Selected Essays of Ludwig Lachmann (Kansas City: Sheed, Andrews and McMeel, 1977): 45-64.

 

Don Lavoie, “Euclideanism versus Hermeneutics: A Reinterpretation of Misesian Apriorism,” in Israel M. Kirzner, ed., Subjectivism, Intelligibility and Economic Understanding (New York: New York University Press, 1986): 192-210.

 

Gerald O’Driscoll and Mario Rizzo, “Static versus Dynamic Subjectivism,” in The Economics of Time and Ignorance (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1985): 17-34; 52-70.

 

Mario Rizzo, “Mises and Lakatos: A Reformulation of Austrian Methodology,” in Israel M. Kirzner, ed., Method, Process, and Austrian Economics: Essays in Honor of Ludwig von Mises (Lexington, Mass.: D.C. Heath, 1982): 53-73.

 

Murray N. Rothbard, “Praxeology: The Methodology of Austrian Economics,” in Edwin Dolan, ed., The Foundations of Modern Austrian Economics (Kansas City: Sheed & Ward, 1976): 19-39.

 

 

                II. Secondary Reading

 

Nicolai Foss, The Austrian School and Modern Economics: Essays in Reassessment (Copenhagen: Handelshøjskolens Forlag, 1994): 181-203.

 

Karl Mittermaier, “Mechanomorphism,” in Israel M. Kirzner, ed., Subjectivism, Intelligibility and Economic Understanding (New York: New York University Press, 1986): 236-251.

 

Stephen Parsons, “The Philosophical Roots on Modern Austrian Economics: Past Problems and Future Prospects,” History of Political Economy, 22 (Summer 1990): 295-319.

 

           

February 25, 2002             ‘Critical Assessments’ in the Literature

 

Pierluigi Barrotta, “A Neo-Kantian Critique of Von Mises’s Epistemology,” Economics & Philosophy, 12 (April 1996): 51-66.

 

Mark Blaug, The Methodology of Economics (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992): 51-82.

 

Theodore Burczak, “The Postmodern Moments of F. A. Hayek’s Economics,” Economics & Philosophy, 10 (1994): 31-58.

 

Theodore Burczak, “Can Subjectivism be Non-Hermeneutic?,” Economics & Philosophy, 10 (1994): 315-317.

 

Bruce Caldwell, Beyond Positivism: Economic Methodology in the Twentieth Century (London: Allen & Unwin, 1982): 99-138.

 

Bruce Caldwell, “Praxeology and Its Critics: An Appraisal,” History of Political Economy, 16 (Fall 1984): 363-379.

 

Bruce Caldwell, “Hayek’s Scientific Subjectivism,” Economics & Philosophy, 10 (1994): 305-314.

               

T. W. Hutchison, The Politics and Philosophy of Economics (New York: New York University Press, 1984): 176-232.

 

D. N. McCloskey, Knowledge and Persuasion in Economics (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1994): 27-52; 313-323.

 

Robert Nozick, “On Austrian Methodology,” Synthese, 36 (1977): 353-392.

 

               

 

MONEY & MACROECONOMICS

 

 

March 4, 2002        The Contributions of the ‘Founders’

 

            I. Primary Reading

 

Eugen Böhm-Bawerk, , Capital and Interest, 3 volumes (South Holland, IL: Libertarian Press, 1959[1884]): Vol. 2, 3-118; 161-176.

 

Carl Menger, Principles of Economics (New York: New York University Press, 1976[1871]): 149-174; 257-285.

 

Carl Menger, “On the Origin of Money,” Economic Journal, June (1892): 239-255.

 

Knut Wicksell, Interest and Prices (New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1965[1898]: 81-121; 223-239.

 

Friedrich von Wieser, “On the Relationship of Costs to Value,” in Israel M. Kirzner, ed., Classics in Austrian Economics, 3 volumes (London: Pickering and Chatto, 1994): Vol. 1, 207-234.

 

 

                II. Secondary Reading

 

A. M. Endres, Neoclassical Microeconomic Theory: The Founding Austrian Version (New York: Routledge, 1997): 146-178.

 

 

March 18, 2002      The ‘Classic’ Statements

 

            I. Primary Reading

 

F. A. Hayek, Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle (New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1966[1928]): 101-192.

 

                F. A. Hayek, Prices and Production (New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1967[1931]): 1-104.

 

F. A. Hayek, “Price Expectations, Monetary Disturbances and Malinvestments” [1933] in ibid., Profits, Interest and Investment (New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1975[1939]): 135-156.

 

F. A. Hayek, Individualism and Economic Order (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980[1948]): 220-254.

 

Ludwig von Mises, The Theory of Money and Credit (Indianapolis: Liberty Classics, 1980[1912]): 41-62; 129-177; 225-243; 377-404.

 

Ludwig von Mises, Human Action (Chicago: Henry Regnery, 1966[1949]): 398-586.

 

 

                II. Secondary Reading

 

Israel M. Kirzner, Ludwig von Mises: The Man and His Economics (Wilmington, Del.: ISI Books, 2001): 121-162.

 

G. R. Steele, The Economics of Friedrich Hayek (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1996): 129-227.

 

 


 

March 25, 2002      The ‘Contemporary’ Restatements

 

            I. Primary Reading

 

                Roger Garrison, Time and Money (New York: Routledge, 2001): 1-122; 221-255.

 

Steve Horwitz, Microfoundations and Macroeconomics: An Austrian Perspective (New York: Routledge, 2001): 1-14; 40-61;65-202.

 

Axel Leijonhufvud, Information and Coordination (New York: Oxford University Press, 1981): 131-202.

 

Murray Rothbard, Man, Economy and State, 2 volumes (Princeton: Van Nostrand, 1962): 273-559; 661-764; 850-878.

 

George Selgin, Less Than Zero: The Case for a Falling Price Level in a Growing Economy (London: IEA, 1997).

 

George Selgin and Lawrence White, “How Would the Invisible Hand Handle Money?,” Journal of Economic Literature, 32 (December 1994): 1718-1749.

 

Lawrence White, The Theory of Monetary Institutions (London: Basil Blackwell, 1999): 1-25; 53-69; 88-137; 180-192; 227-239.

 

 

                II. Secondary Reading

 

Nicolai Foss, The Austrian School and Modern Economics: Essays in Reassessment (Copenhagen: Handelshøjskolens Forlag, 1994): 13-56.

 

 

               

April 1, 2002           ‘Critical Assessments’ in the Literature

 

Tyler Cowen, Risk and Business Cycles: New and Old Austrian Perspectives (New York: Routledge, 1997): 1-12; 76-114.

 

Richard Wagner, “Austrian Cycle Theory: Saving the Wheat while Discarding the Chaff,” Review of Austrian Economics, 12 (1999): 65-80.

 

 

 

MARKET THEORY AND THE PRICE SYSTEM

 

 

April 15, 2002         The Contribution of the ‘Founders’

 

            I. Primary Reading

 

Eugen Böhm-Bawerk, Capital and Interest, 3 volumes (South Holland, IL: Libertarian Press, 1959[1884]): Vol. 2, 205-256.

 

Franz Čuhel, “On the Theory of Needs” [1906], in Israel M. Kirzner, ed., Classics in Austrian Economics, 3 volumes (London: Pickering and Chatto, 1994): Vol. 1, 305-337.

 

Carl Menger, Principles of Economics (New York: New York University Press, 1976[1871]): 175-225.

 

 

                II. Secondary Reading

 

A. M. Endres, Neoclassical Microeconomic Theory: The Founding Austrian Version (London: Routledge, 1997): 60-145.

 

Israel M. Kirzner, “The Entrepreneurial Role in Menger’s System,” Atlantic Economic Journal, 6 (September 1978): 31-45.

 

Laurence Moss, “Carl Menger’s Theory of Exchange,” Atlantic Economic Journal, 6 (September 1978): 17-30.

 

 

 

April 22, 2002         The ‘Classic’ Statements

 

            I. Primary Reading

 

F. A. Hayek, Individualism and Economic Order (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980[1948]): 33-56; 77-208.

 

F. A. Hayek, “Competition as a Discovery Procedure” [1969], in ibid., New Studies in Philosophy, Politics, Economics and the History of Ideas (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1978): 179-190.

 

Fritz Machlup, “Marginal Analysis and Empirical Research,” American Economic Review, 36 (September 1946).

 

Fritz Machlup, “Equilibrium and Disequilibrium: Misplaced Concreteness and Disguised Politics,” The Economic Journal, 68 (March 1958).

 

Fritz Machlup, “Theories of the Firm: Marginalist, Behavioral, Managerial,” American Economic Review, 62 (March 1967): 1-13.

 

Arthur Marget, “Stream Equations and Process Analysis” [1942], in ibid., The Theory of Price (New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1966): 346-403.

 

Hans Mayer, “The Cognitive Value of Functional Theories of Price” [1932], in Israel M. Kirzner, ed., Classics in Austrian Economics, 3 volumes (London: Pickering and Chatto, 1994): Vol. 2, 55-168.

 

Ludwig von Mises, Human Action (Chicago: Henry Regnery, 1966[1949]): 232-397; 689-715.

 


 

                II. Secondary Reading

 

Bruce Caldwell, “Hayek and Socialism,” Journal of Economic Literature, 35 (December 1997): 1856-1890.

 

Israel M. Kirzner, Ludwig von Mises: The Man and His Economics (Wilmington, Del.: ISI Books, 2001): 93-120.

 

 

 

April 29, 2002         The ‘Contemporary’ Restatement

 

            I. Primary Reading

 

Jack High, Maximizing, Action and Market Adjustment (München: Philosophia Verlag, 1990): 125-69.

 

Israel M. Kirzner, The Meaning of Market Process (New York: Routledge, 1992): 38-56.

 

Israel M. Kirzner, “Entrepreneurial Discovery and the Competitive Market Process,” Journal of Economic Literature, 35 (March 1997): 60-85.

 

Ludwig Lachmann, “On the Central Concept of Austrian Economics: Market Process,” in Edwin Dolan, ed., The Foundations of Modern Austrian Economics (Kansas City: Sheed and Ward, 1976): 126-132.

 

Don Lavoie, Rivalry and Central Planning (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1985): 48-116; 145-178.

 

Don Lavoie, National Economic Planning: What is Left? (Washington, DC: CATO, 1985): 25-92.

 

Peter Lewin, Capital in Disequilibrium: The Role of Capital in a Changing World (New York: Routledge, 1999): 15-28; 160-174; 202-212.

 

Gerald O’Driscoll and Mario Rizzo, The Economics of Time and Ignorance (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1985): 71-159.

 

Murray N. Rothbard, Man, Economy and State, 2 volumes (Princeton: Van Nostrand, 1962): 560-660.

 

Frédéric Sautet, An Entrepreneurial Theory of the Firm (New York: Routledge, 2000): 4-54.

 

Esteban Thomsen, Prices and Knowledge: A Market-Process Perspective (New York: Routledge, 1992).

 

 

                II. Secondary Reading

 

Peter Boettke and David Prychitko, “Varieties of Market Process Theory,” in Peter Boettke and David Prychitko, eds., Market Process Theories, 2 volumes (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 1998): ix-xxvii.

 

Sanford Ikeda, “Market-Process Theory and ‘Dynamic’ Theories of the Market,” Southern Economic Journal, 57 (1990): 75-92.

 

Frank Machovec, Perfect Competition and the Transformation of Economics (New York: Routledge, 1995): 14-51; 159-200; 268-293.

 

 

 

May 6, 2002                        ‘Critical Assessments’ in the Literature

 

David Audretsch, William Baumol, and Andrew Burke,” Competition Policy in Dynamic Markets,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19 (2001): 613-634.

 

Harald Benink and Peter Bossaerts, “An Exploration of Neo-Austrian Theory Applied to Financial Markets,” Journal of Finance, 56 (June 2001): 1011-1027.

 

Peter Boettke, David Prychitko, and Steven Horwitz, “Beyond Equilibrium Economics” [1986], reprinted in Peter Boettke and David Prychitko, eds., The Market Process: Essays in Contemporary Austrian Economics (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 1994): 62-79.

 

James Buchanan and Viktor Vanberg, “The Market as a Creative Process,” Economics & Philosophy, 7 (1991): 167-86.

 

Bryan Caplan, “The Austrian Search for Realistic Foundations,” Southern Economic Journal, 65 (April 1999): 823-838.

 

Louis Makowiski and Joseph Ostroy, “Perfect Competition and the Creativity of the Market,” Journal of Economic Literature, 39 (June 2001): 479-535.

 

Andrei Shleifer, Inefficient Markets (New York: Oxford University Press, 2000): 1-27; 175-197.

 

Andrew Yates, “The Knowledge Problem, Entrepreneurial Discovery and Austrian Market Process Theory,” Journal of Economic Theory, 91 (March 2000): 59-85.